September 17, 2024

Dutching stake allocation- consequences

An important corollary of the Dutching stake allocation theorem can be formulated like this:

In Dutching exist a positive number greater than zero by which we can correctly estimate the possible gain of invested money called compound odds:

c.o : H(x1.x2,…xδ)/ δ

where δ is the number of dimensions in which we operate

Proof:

decimal odds is  the inverse of implied probability in the eny nuber of dimension, so in Dutching stake allocation also

Because d.o is really the inverse of implied probability, left equality is valid!

We can continue with left δ-1 equalities:

If we sum up these δ equalities :

Compounded odds  pointing what exact amount of net profit we can earn if we adjust stakes in a manner of Dutching stake allocation

Actually, we proved the next interesting thing:

There is a unique number named compounded odds which pointing what exact amount of net profit we can earn if we adjust stakes in a manner described as Dutching

Or, below the hyperplane which with the coordinate axes of the delta dimensional coordinate system forms a delta dimensional tetrahedron within exists an area within which there is an increased possibility of obtaining revenue

The measure of that potential revenue, a unique number, called compound odds can be calculated by the formula:

Let’s take a closer look at the expression c.o*S
It is similar to d.o*S in case of single selection, or accumulation
d.o*S contains stake plus eventual net profit, so d.o*S= S+ ρ*S because it is generally valid:d.o=1+f.o

The resulting expression, c.o*S has the same meaning.
It may or may not contain net profit because among other conditions it deeply depends on over-round (c.o<1)or under-round(c.o >1)


Discussing Σp(very important)

Σpr =p1 + p2 +…… + pδ

As we know, dealing with bookie offers, 1- Σpr < 0 and Σpr -1>0 is called overround, vigoris, juice, etc

So if we stick with one bookie always must be r < number of all given markets

For example, if we bet on 1. half/2.half in a football game, the market has this structure:
{1,0,2}X(1,0,2}=[(1,1),(1,0),(1,2),(0,1),(0,0),(0,2),(2,1),(2,0),(2,2)}
We deal with 9 possibilities

There is not the slightest chance that the sum of all probabilities in the offer of coefficients will be less than 1
Therefore, it must be taken: r<9

From set {1,0,2}X(1,0,2} we could chose its subset: {1,0),(1,2),(0,1),(0,0),(0,2)}
And of course, first {1,0,2) could be the market for a team1 result in 1half of game, and the second {1,0,2] for team2 in 2. half some other game!!

In this particular case, we deal with accumulation!

In that particular case r=5 , and that is our decision and we are faced with the risk of possibly losing our bet!

“Every betting decision you make has to be judged on its own individual merits and dutching doesn’t change that”

Nigel Channing

                     

The easiest way to get to c.o> 1 is to choose a market, combine it from an offer of different bookies

But then, we entering in the area of arbitrary betting if want to cover all possibilities/outcomes

                  

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

error: Content is protected !!